It is the Tories who have a 30% strategyBy Michael Burke
Ed Miliband is accused of having a ‘35% strategy’, meaning that he is banking on doing only just enough to win an overall majority at the next general election. Polling models suggest that 35% would be enough for Labour to achieve an overall majority in Parliamentary seats. This is because the Tory vote is increasingly concentrated, while Labour’s is far more widely spread geographically.
Since Labour’s electoral strategy has not been divulged to SEB, it is idle to speculate on it, although this has not prevented others from doing so. Instead, it is possible to demonstrate that the Tory policy is based on an electoral strategy that is focused on an even narrower section of the electorate. It is the Tories who have a 30% electoral strategy.
The map below (which the present author first saw published by Ian Wright MP) shows the cumulative effect in English constituencies of cuts under the Coalition government during this parliament. The Tory Party is a fringe grouping in Scotland and is headed in that direction in Wales. Despite repeated attempts it has also failed to resurrect Conservative Unionism in Ireland.
Chart 1. Cumulative effect on change in spending power 2010/11 to 2015/16
The areas in beige have been barely affected by government cuts (although these are averages, there will be many people living in those areas who are badly affected by austerity). The areas in green have experienced no net cuts at all.
By contrast, areas coloured in red have seen a fall in living standards of between 15% and 20%. Those areas coloured deepest red have seen falls of greater than 20% and take in all the large cities, including London. The economic map almost precisely coincides with the electoral map of Britain. The Economist and others are keen to argue that this is a North-South divide in British politics. To that end, they are obliged to perform some logical contortions. In order to make the main divide in British politics North versus South, The Economist excludes the Midlands from the North and excludes London from the South!
The economic response of the Coalition government led by the Tories is to protect and promote those Tory heartlands, as shown in Chart 1 above. SEBhas previously shown how a minority of society, the owners of capital and the rich, are benefitting from the ‘recovery’ in which most people’s living standards continue to fall.
Perhaps the most flagrant policy in this regard is Osborne’s ‘Help to Buy Scheme’. The entire policy of increasing demand for housing while doing nothing to increase supply inevitably leads to higher prices. A number of commentators and economists from the Right have attacked the scheme as an absurd policy, designed solely to boost property prices rather than housing availability. It is a ‘help to get re-elected’ scheme. The resulting property price bubble is concentrated in London and the South-East, and even here there is growing resentment at the unaffordability of housing, not a feel-good factor.
Politically and economically, the Tories are pursuing a core vote strategy. This may not amount to much more than 30% at the next general election, and will certainly be less than the 36.9% they received in 2010. As a result, support for the LibDems has collapsed as this does not at all coincide with the interests of their electoral base, higher-paid workers, professional classes and small business owners.
Labour’s winning electoral strategy should be equally clear and substantially broader. In terms of political geography it should embrace the democratic demands for greater national rights within the British state, as well as finally ending the British presence in Ireland. It needs to have a programme of economic regeneration for the North and the big cities. It should adopt a very large scale programme of council house building with London at its centre-piece. Socially, it needs to be a champion of equality and democracy, tackling the huge inequalities faced by women and tackling the endemic racism of British society, which cannot be done while promising to be tough on immigration.
Above all now, it needs to reverse the policy of austerity which is lowering the living standards of the overwhelming majority and will continue to do so. The Tory policy, of government spending cuts and inducements to the private sector to invest has not worked. A policy of government-led investment is required, combined with other policies that will directly lift standards. The Tory party is pursuing a narrow electoral strategy to shore up its support. Labour can offer something better.
A new situation requires a new analysis, and each new factor in the situation requires a specific and concrete analysis, placing it and its weight correctly in the overall situation.
In world politics, the new situation is that the US was unable to bomb Syria, it finds itself negotiating with, rather than bombing Iran, and its coup in the Ukraine may not be entirely successful in drawing Russia’s neighbour into NATO’s sphere of influence.
This overturns recent history. The overthrow of the Soviet Union in 1991 was accompanied by the US-led Gulf War. Since that time, the US and its various allies have bombed, invaded or intervened in Somalia (twice), Yugoslavia, Haiti, Afghanistan, the Philippines, Liberia, Iraq, the Maghreb, Yemen, Libya, Pakistan, Libya and South Sudan. The US has also led, organised or outsourced countless other interventions, overthrown governments and destabilised economies in pursuit of its interests. There has also been a series of coups and attempted coups in Latin America with varied success, and the so-called ‘colour revolutions’ in Eastern Europe to install pro-US, pro-NATO governments, as well as the US hijacking of the Arab Spring.
However, the economic rise of China has warranted a strategic ‘pivot’ towards Asia in an attempt to curb the rise of the only economy that could rival US supremacy in the foreseeable future. Given this absolute priority and the reduced circumstances of the US economy, it has been necessary to suspend new large-scale direct military interventions elsewhere.
This curb on US power has had immediate and beneficial consequences for humanity. Syria could not be bombed and neither could Iran. In these, Russian opposition to US plans was a key political obstacle, especially as the US wanted to deploy multilateral and multinational forces to do its bidding and needed the imprimatur of the UN Security Council. The US response to this blockage has been to increase pressure on Russia, most dramatically with its ouster of the elected Ukrainian government in a coup and its attempt to breach the country’s agreed neutrality by bringing it into NATO.
This curb on US power, however limited or temporary, should be welcomed by all socialists, by all democrats and simply by all those who desire peace. Instead, we have the strange spectacle that some on the left have raised the charge that Russia is imperialist, or that China is, or countries such as Brazil, or India or South Africa are‘sub-imperialist’!
This is not a coincidence. In the US State Department’s frustration it has produced every type of calumny against Putin, including that he is an imperialist[i] and akin to Hitler. Self-styled socialists who simply echo these charges are not highly amenable to logical argument. But it is vital for socialists to understand the nature of imperialism and its current manifestation[ii].
Lenin’s stated aim in writing the work was to demonstrate that the 1914-1918 war was imperialist (that is an annexationist, predatory, war of plunder) on the part of both sides; it was a war for the division of the world, for the partition and repartition of colonies and spheres of influence of finance capital, and so on.
Furthermore, he argued, that the character of the war, its class character, was determined by the position of the ruling classes of the warring countries and of the whole world, as the ruling classes of the belligerent countries had between them annexed almost the entire world. Therefore, he concluded imperialist wars are absolutely inevitable under such an economic system, as long as private property in the means of production exists[iii].
However, Lenin was categorical in warning that this was a study of imperialism in a given historical epoch and this was specifically (or concretely) ‘a composite picture of the world capitalist system at the beginning of the twentieth century’. As shown below, he also highlighted how this composite might change, as it was already changing.
Therefore it completely contravenes Lenin’s injunctions in this and other works, indeed it is completely alien to the method of Marxism, to abstract from his pamphlet one or two important features of imperialism at this point, and use them as a measuring rule for modern imperialism. Imperialism, like all phenomena, must be analysed concretely, and only after taking all the main factors into account, and so establish its laws of motion. Changing politics
Three decisive changes in world politics have occurred since Lenin wrote his great work. As we shall see, the world economy has not stood still either, like all phenomena it too has continued to ‘flow’, in Lenin’s words.
The first decisive political change was in the contest over who would be the dominant imperialist in the world, which began in 1914 was resolved by 1945. The US had become the single dominant imperialist power and would countenance no serious rivalry from other imperialists. The best they could hope for was to play some subordinate but mutually beneficial role as a junior ally of US imperialism.
The second decisive change took place between in the short period between Lenin’s writing the pamphlet and its later Preface. The Russian Revolution meant that for the first time the working class was able to lay hold of and maintain state power. Since that time, and notwithstanding the overthrow of the Soviet Union, there have been continuously some parts of the globe where the working class holds state power, including Cuba, Viet Nam and Venezuela. Of these workers’ states by far the weightiest in the world economy is China. In all these cases, private property in the means of production is not the dominant form of ownership in the domestic economy. However, all are obliged to operate in a global capitalist system in which imperialism dominates.
Taking advantage of this contradiction, the third change is that the anti-colonial and national liberation struggles were able to free the great bulk of humanity from burden of direct colonial rule, and in some cases this led ultimately to socialist revolution.
These three facts, US supremacy within the imperialist bloc, the continuous existence of workers’ states and the wave of direct decolonisation, are entirely new factors. They are decisive in understanding that the main antagonism in the world is no longer inter-imperialist competition (which has certainly not been abolished).
Now, the pre-eminence of the US and the existence of workers’ states with real political and economic weight means that principal contradiction in world politics is between the US and its imperialist allies versus the workers states and the countries oppressed by imperialism (including the semi-colonial world and the remaining colonies). Of these, the biggest, the weightiest threat to US economic interests is the rise of China. Changing economics
In Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism, Lenin sums up the main economic features of imperialism in that period. To some readers these are well-known, but they are worth repeating here. Worth repeating too is his own characterisation of this definition, which is that it was a special stage in the historical development of capitalism (which has continued to develop).
The five features identified by Lenin are as follows: (1) the concentration of production and capital has developed to such a high stage that it has created monopolies which play a decisive role in economic life; (2) the merging of bank capital with industrial capital, and the creation, on the basis of this “finance capital”, of a financial oligarchy; (3) the export of capital as distinguished from the export of commodities acquires exceptional importance; (4) the formation of international monopolist capitalist associations which share the world among themselves, and (5) the territorial division of the whole world among the biggest capitalist powers is completed.
Lenin’s starting-point is the concentration of production into monopolies, which is the basis of imperialism. This concentration is the inevitable outcome of ‘free competition’ between capitalists and has as a result risen exponentially since the pamphlet was written. Concentration means capitalist rivals are eliminated, and so increased profits require expansion overseas.
The increase in concentration of production and trend towards monopolisation can be illustrated by the fact that the largest companies in the world are now larger than most countries. The tenth largest company in the world has revenues of well over US$200bn, and only 40 countries in the world have a greater level of annual GDP. In Lenin’s time, 44% of all US industrial output was carried out by just 3,000 firms. Now the output of just 130 firms is equivalent to 48% of US GDP[iv].
Concentration of production within the imperialist bloc has also increased. The dominance of the US is evident from the fact that it boasts nearly one-third of the leading Fortune 500 global firms, the same as its next three imperialist rivals together. At the turn of the twentieth century US Steel was the largest company in the world, with average net profits of US$34million. This is equivalent just under US$1 billion in today’s terms. In 2013 the most profitable company in the world was Apple, with profits of US$42bn. Aside from the few loss-makers, most companies in the Fortune 500 had profits far in excess of US$1 billion in 2013.
The role of banks has also increased, but in an even more pronounced way. Lenin uses detailed data to show that the 9 leading banks in Germany held deposits of 10 billion German Marks. Two banks in the US, owned by the plutocrats JP Morgan and Rockefeller had deposits equivalent to 11 billion German Marks. These were equivalent to US$2.4 billion and US$2.6 billion in 1913 exchange rates. In today’s terms these are equivalent to US$56 billion and US$62 billion respectively. In 2013, Germany’s largest bank Deutsche Bank alone had deposits equivalent to US$727 billion. JP Morgan Chase is the biggest bank in the US which in 2013 held deposits of US$ 1,288 billion. At the same time, Lenin identifies the growth in traded securities to the equivalent of 479 billion French Francs. This is the equivalent of US$ 2,700 billion in today’s terms. But this is a fraction of the current level of international claims held by banks in the imperialist centres, of US$32,859 billion[v].
Taken together these data show that the main features identified by Lenin, the concentration of capital and monopoly and the increasing dominance of finance capital have both become more pronounced and more dominant features of imperialism.
However, value can only be extracted if it is produced. Just as imperialism is a parasitic extension of capitalism, the dominance of finance capital is a parasitic characteristic of imperialism, which leads to its decay. Parasitism and decay
Under a system of super-exploitation, the capitalist has a diminishing incentive to develop the productive forces of the economy as profits can be increased simply by increasing the scope of territory and the number of slaves held by the slave-owners. This was noted by Marx in his analysis of the Southern slave states of America.
In a different context, imperialism too is a system of super-exploitation, one which attempts to embrace the whole world. Marx had earlier shown that the first imperial power, Britain in Ireland, had benefited from a higher rate of exploitation in its colony, with the imperial power ‘pocketing the excess’ profits even beyond the rate of exploitation in their own domestic market. As the brutality and rapaciousness of the regime increases, so too does its parasitical nature. This leads to decay and its vulnerability to competition from a more vigorous system of production.
At the beginning of the twentieth century Britain was the premier trading nation in the world, via its empire. However, Lenin points out that Britain’s profits from its foreign and colonial trade was just one-fifth of its profits derived from its overseas financial investments. Britain had already become a ‘rentier state’, primarily living off these investments.
Britain had run a trade deficit, the value of imports exceeding the value of exports for most of the period from the 1890s to the outbreak of the 1914-18 war[vi]. But the very high level of interest income (or rent) on its overseas possessions meant that the balance on the current account (the combined balance of trade in goods and services plus overseas interest payments) remained in surplus. This overall surplus on the current account ended in the 1930s. Repeated devaluations of the overvalued pound frequently redressed this imbalance by making exports cheaper and increasing the value of overseas interest payments in pound sterling terms. The discovery of North Sea oil also gave a temporary boost, but deficits on the current account have become such a fixed feature of the British economy since that in some official data it is sometimes referred to as the current account deficit, rather than the current account balance.
The deficit on the current account must have an off-setting item to balance it. This is the capital account, the net flows of capital rather than of interest payments or dividends. When Britain fell into a current account deficit in the 1930s it was obliged to become a net importer of capital to off-set it.
As noted above, Lenin had identified the export of capital as one of the key features of imperialism at the beginning of the twentieth century. Only the most hide-bound or scholastic reading of Lenin would then argue that in the 1930s Britain passed from being an imperialist nation to an oppressed one. Instead, the parasitism and decay of British imperialism has led it into a new and more decrepit, leech-like phase. Where Britain has trod the United States has followed. Capital importers
The much greater size of the US domestic market, the consequent scope for increasing the division of labour and the greater productivity of its industries all meant the capitalist mode of production retained a degree of vigour there that had long become a distant memory in Britain. This was reinforced by the pre-eminent position of the US following the 1914 to 1945 world wars.
However the US too has become a net importer of capital over a different timescale. This is shown in Chart 1 below. The US became an importer of capital because the growth of the economy was insufficient to maintain both the growth in living standards of the population and to fund the Viet Nam war. The US became an importer of capital in the course of the Viet Nam war and in order to pay for it.
Chart 1. US Current Account Balance 1960 to 1980, US$ billions
Source: Federal Reserve Economic Data
The US did not become an economically oppressed nation while it
was raining more bombs on Viet Nam, Laos and Cambodia than were dropped in the
whole of the Second World War. Instead, imperialism
and the dominant imperialist power has entered a new phase, where it sucks in
capital from the rest of the world. It does so without in advance being
either a net exporter of goods or of capital.
As Lenin and a host of commentators had shown, in an earlier phase imperialism
had been an exporter of capital. By the early 1970s the US (and Britain, long
before) had become importers of capital.
Persistently incurring new net debts will tend to run down any existing net
stock of overseas capital. This is precisely what has happened. The US, as well
as France and Britain are imperialist powers who own no net overseas assets, that is to say, their
overseas debts are greater than their overseas assets. This is shown in Table 1
below.
Table 1. Net International Investment Position 2012, US$ billions
Source: IMF, International Financial Statistics[vii]
The US is the world’s biggest net overseas debtor. It requires
capital inflows to support the living standards of the population while
maintaining the same level of military spending as the rest of the top 10
nations put together. These debts in return require interest payments, which in
turn piles up further debt.
Yet the most remarkable feature of the current economic aspects of imperialism
is that the US, a country which has no net assets but only net debts, achieves
a surplus on its investment income account. The net flows on the investment
income account are shown in Table 2 below.
Table 2. Investment Income Account, Net Flows, 2012, US$ billions
Source: World Bank, Data, Net Primary Income[viii]
Taken
together these five imperialist powers have effectively no net overseas assets,
as the net assets of Japan and Germany are effectively balanced by the net
debts of the US, France and the UK. Yet in 2012 they received a net US$526
billion in net payments of interest and dividends from the rest of the world.
Within this bloc, the US is clearly pre-eminent. It extracted more
interest from the rest of the world than Japan, despite having net debts
greater than the level of Japan’s net assets. France and the UK were junior
partners in this role. By contrast, both Japan and Germany are able to sustain
trade surpluses because of accumulated levels of productivity (and in Japan’s
case severe restrictions on imports). For them, there is no imperative to
engineer investment income surpluses, these are a natural outcome of their
trade-driven accumulation of overseas assets. Even so, along with France and
the UK, they too play a supporting role in the global system of imperialism and
benefit from it.
[* The UK is undergoing a particular period of turmoil in its overseas
accounts, associated with the continuing crisis of its banking system and their
overseas operations. In the prior year the surplus was $42 billion. But it
remains to be seen to what extent the UK can recover this position].
Finance Capital
A capitalist economy is one in which there is generalised commodity production.
Money is the universal commodity, standing in for all other commodities in the
process of exchange. The control over the direction or allocation of money
capital therefore becomes decisive in the development of capitalism itself. The
medium for this allocation is the banks[ix].
As a result, the degree of concentration of capital and the dominance of
monopolies depends on the financial capacity of the banks. The scale of
necessary investment requires access to large-scale savings. The elimination of
rivals requires financial resources. So, the creation of Ford Motors, Standard
Oil and AEG relied on the emergence of JP Morgan, Rockefeller and Deutsche Bank
respectively. This control over the allocation capital places the banks in an
increasingly dominant position in the capitalist economy. Dominance over the
global financial system is the essential condition for dominance over an entire
economic system dominated by finance capital.
As the dominant force in the global financial system, the US directs resources
for its own needs. It charges vastly higher rates of interest when it recycles
capital overseas than it is willing to pay. This explains how it is possible
for the US to draw in interest income when it owns no net assets. At the same
time, the US and its junior partners in France and the UK have not grown as
rapidly as the world economy over a prolonged period, and yet they are
continually able to draw in capital from the rest of the world. This too is
only possible because of the US dominance over the global financial system,
with Britain and France playing an important subordinate role.
The US dominates all global transactions through the trading pre-eminence of
the US Dollar, which accounts for approximately 85% of all foreign exchange
transactions.[x] Firms seeking to raise capital
privately are inspected by the US-dominated ratings’ agencies. Governments are
frequently obliged to apply to the IMF or World Bank, where the US dominates.
The obligatory criteria under which these finances are disbursed, or not,
comprises privatisations, reduced government spending, lower living standards
and financial ‘liberalisation’. These have the effect of allowing greater
access to domestic markets for the imperialist powers, their firms and their
banks, and most especially allows access to domestic savings, which are
required to fund the external deficits of the US and the other imperialists. It
is no accident that the ideology underpinning these criteria is called the
‘Washington Consensus’. It amounts to dominance over the financial system which
dominates the world and gives the US privileged access to its resources.
This is far removed from the era of ‘free trade’, between firms and nations
which ended by the turn of the twentieth century. In any event this frequently
involved robbing the colonies of goods or raw materials for far below their
value, or in many cases simply outright plunder. It is even further removed
from the trade of one large country with another, say Brazil with Venezuela or
China in Africa. These can be mutually beneficial trading relationships, even
while governed by laws of the capitalist market.
Instead, the parasitic imperialist powers are able to conjure capital and
interest from the rest of the world, seemingly out of thin air and on a
repeated basis. It is comparable to free trade only in the way that an armed
robber is akin to a market stallholder. In both cases money changes hands, but
US dominance over the global financial system leaves as little in return as the
robber. And this is not a one-off, but it is a continuous flow of capital.
It is only possible to rob someone repeatedly if a knife is held to their
throat. The extraordinary US expenditure on its military and the willingness of
its French and British aides de camp to support its military adventures (even
their disappointment when the US was obliged to refrain from bombing Syria) is
explained by this imperative to plunder the rest of the world. Military dominance and repeated
shows of military force are necessary to underpin a system of global financial
extortion.
The negative effects of imperial domination are not most frequently felt
through war. This is just the most extreme symptom. Instead, a consequence of
the dominance of the US and its interests in global finance is that even any
changes in the economic or monetary conditions of the US reverberate globally.
Abrupt changes in the US repeatedly manifest themselves as regional or even
global crises. This is shown in Chart 2 below.
Chart 2. US Long-Term Interest Rates and Financial Market Crises
Source: Federal Reserve Economic Data
The
chart above shows long-term US interest rates and some of the main financial
market crises. The yields on US government debt change if there is an
alteration in the balance of supply and demand for capital in the US. This was
the case when Reagan came to office and hugely expanded the US budget deficit.
It has also been the case with (increasingly modest) economic revivals in 1994,
in 1997 and the very mild economic upturn in 2012. In all cases the increased
demand for capital in the US led to a rise in US long-term interest rates.
The consequence was that capital flowed out of the semi-colonial
world and into the US, leaving the former in crisis. This occurred with the
Latin America debt crisis of the early 1980s, the global financial crisis in
the early 1990s, the Asian financial crisis of 1997 and 1998. The recent
‘emerging market’ slowdown is only milder to date because the rising demand for
capital in the US to fund rising consumption has been extremely modest by
historical standards. Yet among the countries most affected by this slowdown
include Brazil, Russia, South Africa, Turkey[xi],
and so on, precisely those countries which are foolishly described as
sub-imperialist, or even in Russia’s case, without the diminishing prefix.
It is only those countries who are able impose capital controls that can partly
insulate themselves from being a store of savings for the US (and face fierce
opposition from the US for doing so). This imperial dependence on capital
inflows is the reason that the US, and its proxies like the IMF are so adamant
that capital movements be ‘liberalised’.
In each case after these major crises the subsequent outflow of capital from
the semi-colonial countries restored the US domestic balance of supply and
demand for savings and so US long-term interest rates declined. But the outflow
of capital left devastation in its wake in the semi-colonial countries
affected.
Increased parasitism, further decay
The impact of US dominance is felt not only in the colonial and semi-colonial
countries but also in the subordinate imperialist countries themselves. As
noted above, in 1994 there was a global financial crisis provoked by an
increased demand for capital in the US which affected all countries unevenly.
While the UK and France attempt to benefit directly from the dominance of the
US and the role of global finance, Japan and Germany remain more closely
related to the archetypal imperialist power of the early twentieth century.
Highly competitive industries and persistent trade surpluses have previously
allowed the build-up of a stock of overseas assets from which German and
Japanese imperialism draw interest from the rest of the world. Consequently,
they have had less incentive to support domestic finance at the expense of
domestic industry. As a result Japan and Germany have much less to gain from
the increased dominance of US-led global finance in the worldwide system of
imperialism.
After 1945, the US aim of bolstering capitalist allies as a bulwark against the
Soviet Union prioritised the rebuilding of war-ravaged Japan and Germany. This
was state intervention to preserve the capitalist system. But it was only after
the US had established its supreme dominance over the rest of the world,
including the subordination of these other imperialist powers through war.
The weight of the imperialist economies is not static, either as a group or
individually. They have undergone a series of dramatic changes. The only
constant is US dominance. Chart 3 below shows the relative weight of these five
imperialist economies in the world economy, both individually and as a group.
The data is shown in the table below.
Three distinct dates are chosen. 1913 represents a snapshot of the world
economy on the eve of 1914-1918 war. 1951 represents the post-1945 settlement.
This is also the highest recorded point of imperialist power on a world scale
as accounted for by share of world GDP and is also the highest recorded level
for the weight of the US in the global economy. 2008 is the final data
available from Maddison before his death, and of course coincides with the
onset of the global financial crisis.
Chart 3
Source: Author’s calculation from Maddison data
The
high-point of these imperialist powers in terms of share of world GDP was 1951.
There has been a sharp decline since that time (which has almost certainly been
deepened by the effects of the crisis). Within that bloc, the US has returned
to its former starting point a century ago, whereas most of the other
imperialist powers have declined in a more marked way. The UK has experienced
the most spectacular fall of all, its weight in the world economy declining by
two-thirds in a hundred years. Japan is the partial exception to this rule,
having been only on the verge of becoming an imperial power at the beginning of
the twentieth century and being utterly devastated by war and nuclear bombing
by the early 1950s.
This still left just 9.5% of the world’s population in these 5 countries to
enjoy the benefits of one-third of world output in 2008. Within those countries
a tiny minority of the population takes the lion’s share. All manner of
chauvinist and racist explanations are advanced for this unequal distribution
of global income, and the accumulated wealth it brings. But in reality it is
only possible if most of the world is dominated by a global system of imperialism, the forcible transfer of incomes
and wealth from most of the world to a minority of it. This system includes
ideological, legal, institutional, commercial and financial strands. All of
these are underpinned by the aggressive exercise of military dominance, led by
the US.
A century ago, Britain had already become a ‘rentier nation’, living off its
overseas income. The factual verdict on this strategy in terms of delivering
growth is devastating. By contrast, Japan’s post-War success was built on very
high levels of investment and favoured nation status in its trade relationships
with the US. Japanese investment as a proportion of GDP rose to what was then
an unprecedented level of 30% of GDP and in consequence GDP growth accelerated
to over 8% per annum.
However this period is already at an end. The Japanese domestic economy has not
been accumulating net new capital for some years and the structural trade
surpluses have become deficits. Growth has also stagnated for 25 years and it
seems probable that like the US, France and the UK, Japan’s net overseas assets
will dwindle towards zero (or below).
A decisive blow was struck by the US against both Japan and West Germany in the
late 1960s. Both countries had been growing more strongly than the US over a
considerable period based on much higher levels of investment. Using the
pressure of its military relationships, in a series of measures the US forced
sharp revaluations of both the Japanese Yen and the Deutsche Mark. It suspended
the convertibility of the US Dollar and finally collapsed the entire post-WWII
Bretton Woods financial system. In this way it was able to disguise a
substantial devaluation of the US Dollar as a widespread but piecemeal
revaluation of other major currencies, while its grip on Middle East oil
ensured this did not lead to an outright balance of payments crisis in the US.
The effect was not to increase US growth but to slow both the Japanese and
German economies for a generation, just as it had used the combination of its
military and financial muscle to devastating effect against France and the UK
during the Suez crisis in 1956. The US later repeated this feat particularly in
relation to Japan, by redirecting Japanese capital towards the US arms race to
bankrupt the Soviet Union in the 1980s. The most important outcome was the
overthrow of the Soviet Union and its reduction to the status of a
semi-colonial country, primarily producing raw materials for the (US-dominated)
international markets. A side-effect was to foster the collapse of Japanese
growth into stagnation, which has been unaltered since 1990.
Inter-imperialist rivalry has not been abolished. But the US has used a
combination of its financial and military dominance to ensure its own dominance
within the imperialist bloc, even as that bloc has been in relative decline.
Conclusion
The concentration of capital and the dominance of finance capital have both
become more pronounced features of global capitalism in the current phase of
imperialism.
Simultaneously, the decayed and parasitical ‘rentier nation’ that Britain had
already become over a century ago is now the norm for the imperialist countries
as a whole and for its dominant country, the United States.
Like an ancient despot, the US and its allies draw in tribute from the rest of
the world in the form of a continuous inflow of capital. There is even a
substantial net inflow of interest income, even though they possess no net
overseas assets, only liabilities.
The main mechanism for this worldwide extortion is the US dominance over the
global financial system, which is itself the dominant sector of capitalism.
This is only possible because it is underpinned by the vast military resources
of the US, which are far greater than all its major rivals combined, and which
it exercises repeatedly and brutally.
Like Britain before it, the US has become a ‘rentier nation’, whose main
overseas income is derived from the exaction of interest and other payments
rather than net trade. But this has entered a new phase, where the tribute of
interest income continues to flow even though there are no assets on which it
is based. Without any net overseas assets, this is only possible because of its
status as imperial power. Imperialism
is a global system of super-exploitation, directed by control over finance
capital and supported by military dominance. The
sole imperial super-power is the US, supported by its allies.
Because imperialism has entered a more decrepit phase does not make it more
benign. On the contrary. The US relentlessly seeks to extend its interlocking
systems of military alliances, trade treaties and financial predominance
because it is in relative decline. The vampire always seeks fresh blood.
Using ‘imperialism’ as a term of abuse, or even as a synonym for a large
trading nation, albeit one possessing nuclear weapons, is to rob it of all
scientific value. The fact that US imperialism can occasionally be challenged
or stymied by some combination of semi-colonial countries and worker’s states
acting in concert does not alter the essential meaning. Instead, these
challenges are a reflection of the relative economic decline of the imperialist
powers in general combined with a growing and related war-weariness on the part
of the population. The US insistence on its own supremacy within the
imperialist bloc has only exacerbated that collective decline, while preserving
its own dominant status.
Rather than echo the frustrations of the US State Department, socialists and
communists welcome the current impotence of the US, for however long it lasts
and however limited it is. In 1997 a triumphalist US imperialism set out its
bold plan to brook no global or regional opposition and to be able to fight two
major wars simultaneously[xii].
In 2013 the US and its allies were unable to begin bombing Syria.
Imperialism is the enemy of all humanity and its set-backs or defeats are a
cause for celebration as they represent an advance for all humankind and the
struggle for socialism.
[ii] As
the US became free to engage in increased military adventures with the collapse
of the Soviet Union, there arose a concerted effort to disguise this by arguing
that ‘imperialism’ was a diffuse and unspecific phenomenon. Hardt and Negri led
the way in ‘Empire’arguing that ‘imperialism has no
address.’ Imperialism is a global system of exploitation, but it has a sole
superpower protagonist which is headquartered in Washington DC.
[iii] This
essay cannot possibly do justice to the scope of Lenin’s work, which relied on
exhaustive and voluminous research in a host of languages. The notebooks for
his pamphlet encompass hundreds of works, in Volume 39 of his Collected Workshttps://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/cw/volume39.htm . However, with access to modern and
publicly available databases it is possible to analyse some of the most
important features identified by him and to update them in light of factually
altered conditions. This can be done without the volume of work that Lenin was
obliged to do, and should be done by socialists seeking to understand the
development of capitalism.
[ix] Lenin
drew on Hilferding’s ‘Finance Capital’http://www.marxists.org/archive/hilferding/1910/finkap/ which analysed the dominance of
finance capital beginning with the role of money which ‘stands in the place of’
all other commodities.
Facts can be a very severe judge. Either economic structures, the models used to explain them and economic policies work, or they don’t. The factual verdict alone can determine who was right, what was successful, what economic system works best.
The chart below is reproduced from The Economist. It shows the change in the IMF’s own estimates and forecasts of the level of US and Chinese GDP. Previously the IMF’s projections were that China would surpass the US as the world’s largest economy in 2019. Its revised estimates are that this will now occur at the end of this year. From 2015 onwards, when anyone refers to the world’s largest economy this will be China, not the US.
Chart 1. IMF Estimates & Projections of US & China GDP, PPP $ trillions
By any standards, this is a momentous econmic event. The leading position in the world economy does not change with great frequency. The US surpassed China’s GDP at some time around 1890, having already overtaken Britain in in 1872. (The Financial Times is incorrect to place this earlier data as the key turning-point- it seems to have ignored China altogether).
In this sense the current reversal is a return to the norm. China’s economy, with a population of 1.3 billion people should be larger than the US. At the same, this higher population level means that per capita GDP is still much below countries like Britain or the US, although this gap too is narrowing rapdly.
As a result, it would be foolish to argue Britain should ‘copy’ China. Different geographies, different relationships with the world economy, different histories and different levels of current economic development would make that an impossibility.
But the Chinese economy has delivered exceptionally strong growth, and grown much more rapidly than the Westen economies over a very prolonged period. In 30 years of the process of reform and opening up from 1978 to 2008 it has raised average living standards from the British level of the 15th century to the same as Britain in 1948. No doubt the advance since 2008 has been equally impressive (probably to something like the early 1960s in Britain).
Larry Elliott in The Guardian points out that Chinese per capita incomes are still way below those of the US. This is true. But the divergence in these trends is also marked. The population of the US has been growing more rapidly than China, while the US economy has been growing much more slowly. This had led to two effects. The first is that in the same 40-year period Chinese per capita GDP has gone from being approximately 5 per cent of the US level to over 20 per cent by 2008.
The second effect is that the growth in population is only a small fraction of the overall contribution to Chinese growth and is a very large contribution to US growth. This is shown in the Table below.
Table 1. US, China, GDP, per capita GDP and population growth 1990-2008
(average annual compound rate, %)
Source: Maddison
The result is that Chinese GDP has been growing by over 5% more than the US over a prolonged period and that Chinese per capita GDP has been growing by over 5.5% more than the US. This growth gap increased during the slump but was resumed again in 2013, when Chinese GDP grow by 7.4% and the US grew by 2.3%.
Mathematically, the effect of compounding is anything that grows annually by 5% will double in size every 15 years. On relative terms, if the current growth gap were maintained the Chinese economy would be double the size of the US economy by not later than 2030. Living standards will catch up later, only because the starting-point is lower.
It would seem foolish to wait until China has achieved living standards comparable to the richest countries in the world before recognising that something could be learnt from its continuous growth.
This is especially pertinent in Britain. The relative decline of the British economy has taken place over such a prolonged period, and had been so pronounced that there is an entire cottage industry devoted to discussing it. A Google search for ‘book + British economic decline’ yields an enormous number of results.
Yet the reality of Britain’s spectacular economic decline barely registers in public debate about the British economy.Currently a short-lived and debt-driven rise in consumption has been enough for public commentary to become dominated by claims about the strongest recovery in the G7. This is despite the fact that this is the weakest British recovery on record, and (except Italy) all the rest of the G7 have recovered more strongly than Britain.
In reality, economic analysis has mainly become a branch of commentary on the electoral fortunes of the Tory Party. It is no accident that both the electoral support for the Tory Party and the British economy have been in relative decline since the beginning of the 1950s.
By contrast, anyone wishing to produce policies that would improve British economic performance should study what has been happening in China for decades. There are a number of factors but the key driving force behind continued Chinese growth and improving living standards and British stagnation and relative decline is the proportion of GDP directed to investment. This is illustrated starkly in the chart below from the Office of National Statistics. This shows the proportion of GDP devoted to investment is selected major economies.
Chart 2. Gross Fixed Capital Formation, % of GDP
Source: ONS
Britain has had the lowest share of GDP directed towards investment for many decades and it has been on a downward trend since the late 1980s. The Chinese ‘reform and opening up’ process began with exceptionally high levels of investment as a proportion of GDP and this has been on a rising trend. Although other factors are important, this is the main driving force behind the differential in growth and the change in living standards.
There is nothing inevitable about learning from the successes of others. It is quite possible to continue to muddle along with stagnation and decline for a very prolonged period. But ignoring reality cannot change it. The facts are that China is an astonishing economic success, and Britain has experienced one of the most spectacular relative declines in economic history. Learning from the Chinese experience, and applying its lessons to the specific conditions of other national economies will be an important contribution to economic policy around the world in the decades to come.
Recent Comments